The Benefits of Government Spending
In July
2016 I showed [1], in a very
simple and straightforward way, how raising taxes and spending the money thus
raised can cause an immediate increase in GDP, while at the same
time allowing increased expenditure on infrastructure. My simple model (detailed
in Table 2 below, and in [1]) shows how
money is recycled; one man’s spending is another man’s income, and so on
repeatedly, towards a limit. My analysis has not been widely heeded by the
media, and maybe it should be restated. It also raises a number of issues that
I did not discuss, such as: who should spend our money — the citizen or the
state, and is VAT better than income tax?
I extend the analysis and the discussion here.
In Table
1 below, I start with an notional GDP of 100 (arbitrary units) and using the
estimates discussed earlier (and listed in Table 2) for amount spent on raw materials,
infrastructure, luxury goods, taken in tax, or wasted, I come up with different
percentages of GDP recycled depending on the tax regime (and my assumptions on
how the tax is spent – see Table 2). The recycled GDP will itself split as
before, and some of it will itself be recycled. But this is not an infinite
regression; there is a mathematical limit given by the formula 1/(1-x), where x is the fraction recycled (e.g. 0.556). We see
that recycling adds considerably to the final GDP, and more so in the high-tax
regimes.
I do not think this point has been often made in the literature generally
available to the public: that raising the level of taxation can increase
GDP.
Table 1. Initial GDP set at 100
arbitrary units. With recycling it swells to > 220
Income tax rate (p/£)
|
20
|
30
|
20
|
30
|
VAT tax rate (p/£)
|
20
|
20
|
30
|
30
|
Percentage of GDP recycled (=x)
|
55.6
|
57.4
|
56.4
|
58.1
|
Total Additional GDP at limit (i.e. 1/(1-x))
|
225.2
|
234.7
|
229.4
|
238.7
|
Total final GDP including initial injection
|
325.2
|
334.7
|
329.4
|
338.7
|
Percentage of GDP spent on Raw
Materials
|
36.0
|
31.5
|
34.0
|
29.7
|
Percentage of GDP spent on
Infrastructure
|
5.6
|
7.4
|
6.4
|
8.1
|
Percentage of GDP wasted
|
2.8
|
3.7
|
3.2
|
4.1
|
Percentage of GDP spent by citizens
|
72.0
|
63.0
|
68.0
|
59.5
|
Percentage of GDP spent on VAT-able
goods
|
32.0
|
28.0
|
28.0
|
24.5
|
Percentage of GDP spent on VAT-free
goods
|
40.0
|
35.0
|
40.0
|
35.0
|
Percentage of GDP collected in
tax
|
28.0
|
37.0
|
32.0
|
40.5
|
There are a number of other points that can be illustrated
with this simple model besides that just made about the importance of recycling
GDP.
Crucial to the effect of GDP recycling lies the question of
what the government does with the taxes it collects. In the model here, it is
assumed that some is spent on infrastructure, and it will be noted that higher
taxes allow a proportionally higher annual spend on infrastructure (and waste).
But a much larger fraction of government income is assumed to be spent on
salaries (nurses, police, teachers, etc.), and on benefits (which I have
treated as GDP, for it will be spent as such). To keep the modelling simple I
have assumed the same split of government resources in each tax regime; so
higher grovernment revenue pours more money into the pockets of millions of
people. Hence the positive effect on GDP. If the model allowed foreign trade,
and people spent their money on foreign cars, the spent money would not recycle
as our GDP; it would figure in the economy of the car-makers.
You might wonder why this route of “Tax and Spend” has not
recommended itself to governments before now. But of course, taxes take money
out of the pockets of the wage-earners. Spending power is particularly hit for
what I have called “voluntary spending” or “VAT-able spending”; essentials are
slightly protected. Few politicians care to campaign for votes with a proposal
to raise taxes, even if that is the sensible thing to do.
Table 2. Variables
used in the model and values assumed in calculations. Only the GDP (i.e.
the ‘wages’) is recycled. The model assumes no foreign trade. ‘Waste’ refers to
submarines and paperclips. If any reader has accurate data on these issues they
can insert their own figures here, and write to me.
Variable
|
Symbol
|
Value assumed
|
Units
|
Input GDP for round 1
|
a
|
100
|
Arbitrary, e.g. B£
|
‘Average’ income tax rate
|
b
|
20 or 30
|
Pence/£
|
‘Average’ VAT rate
|
c
|
20 or 30
|
Pence/£
|
Portion of net income spent
VAT-free
|
d
|
0.5
|
|
Part of VAT-free -> wages
|
e
|
0.5
|
|
Part of VAT-free -> raw
material
|
1-e
|
0.5
|
|
After VAT, part -> wages (i.e.
GDP)
|
f
|
0.5
|
|
After VAT, part -> raw
material
|
1-f
|
0.5
|
|
Fraction of total tax on wages
|
g
|
0.5
|
|
Fraction of total tax on
benefits
|
h
|
0.2
|
|
Fraction total tax on
infrastructure
|
i
|
0.2
|
|
Fraction of total tax on waste
|
1-(g+h+i)
|
0.1
|
There was a theory, promulgated by some macro-economists,
that lowering
taxes will leave more money in the hands of the spending public, who will spend
it and boost GDP. But will they spend it? And what will they spend it on? It is
paternalistic to suppose that the government will spend more wisely than the
citizen; paternalistic and perhaps also over-optimistic. Our governments since
the credit squeeze of 2007 have shown no great wisdom in leading the way
towards economic recovery. They have beggared the health service, given tax
cuts to those on super-tax rates, and flooded the banks with fake money,
ostensibly to cause inflation. On the present model we can see why tax cuts can
fail to simulate the economy, when accompanied by spending cuts.
References
No comments:
Post a Comment