Cut or Spend
Why is the "austerity" question still being debated?
Still the battle rages! Ann Pettifor and Veronica Chick
(Financial Times 4th Oct 2010) declared (ex cathedra) that cutting government spending (or increasing taxes)
would not decrease the deficit, but increase it. But no one headed. The Nobel Prize winner Paul
Krugman ran a column week after week with the same argument. In June 2012, he
and Layard published "A
manifesto for economic sense" [1], calling for a policy of fiscal
stimulus to reduce unemployment and foster growth. Yet the ordinary citizens and
their ordinary governments are very loath to spend further money as a way to
reduce the deficit; it is too counter-intuitive.
Part of the argument is easy: "A sovereign state is not the same as a household." Obviously! But that point is not enough to persuade the averagely cautious to borrow money on world markets in order to "restore growth". Though I have grappled before with this topic [2], I take it up again now, and attempt a
more quantitative approach. I do not have the mental power to follow an
algebraic analysis, and nor will my intended readership. But I have evolved a robust and glaringly simple approach to numerical problems of this
sort. I assume very rough figures for the way salaries enter into the
prices of goods, and have simplified grossly to expose the argument, but I
believe that this approach could be 'tuned' rather accurately if the correct
splits (of one sum between its 2 or 3 parts) were determined and inserted. My conclusion is startling.
Imagine for simplicity the United Kingdom to be a closed
community with no external trade. I can therefore equate GDP with the sum of
all income in the country [3].
Suppose, initially, that the annual GDP is 1trillion GB£. (1Tr£) [Table 1;
Stage 1] Suppose that the government
collects 20% of all income as income tax and 20% of non-exempt spending as VAT.
The income tax revenue stream is therefore 0.2Tr£ [Stage 2].
If all the remaining net income (0.8Tr£) were spent, half on
VATable commodities, and half on VAT-free items [Stage 3], the VAT stream would be 0.08Tr£, as
that is 20% of 0.4Tr£ [Stage 4]. Of the VAT-free portion of GDP, I am going to
assume that half represents salaries for farmers and shopkeepers, etc, while
half is the cost of "raw materials". The salary portions, of course,
constitutes part of the eventual GDP [Stage 4]. (It is arguable that much of
"raw material" is also income, e.g. for the forester.)
The VATable portion of net income, after deduction of the
VAT, is spent on our voluntary purchases. I shall assume (in the first
instance) that this also will be distributed 50:50 between raw materials and
salaries (of boat-builders, opera singers and the like). The latter, as before,
becomes part of GDP.
Let us now spend the tax we have collected (IT+V) [Stage 5], and
suppose that 50% is salaries of civil servants, soldiers, nurses, etc.; so eventually
part of GDP. A further 20% might go on benefits (which I shall count as GDP in
that it will be treated as income by its recipients), 20% on infrastructure,
leaving 10% as waste (e.g. paper clips, rubber bands, and shredded paper.) [Stage
6]
In this very crude first analysis it seems that, with an
initial GDP of 1Tr£, a certain amount is lost to the economy on raw materials,
infrastructure, and waste (0.444Tr£), while the remaining 0.556Tr£ recycles and becomes part of the final
GDP of 1.556Tr£. (This may relate to what economists know as the 'fiscal multiplier'
[4].) [5]
In Table 2 the argument is repeated with none of the
assumptions changed except that VAT
and income tax are both raised to 30%. It turns out that the losses to the economy now amount to
0.4175 with 0.5825 returning to GDP to produce an eventual GDP of 1.582Tr£.
The surprizing result is that raising taxes, in addition to improving
infrastructure, has raised GDP, for the taxes in this model are largely returned
to the economy in the form of salaries and benefits.
Table 1. Recycling of GDP with VAT and income tax at 20% (Units=Trillion £GB)
Initial GDP=1Tr£
|
||||||||
Inc tax
0.2
|
Net income
0.8
|
|||||||
VATable spending
0.4 |
VAT exempt (rent, food)
0.4 |
|||||||
VAT
0.08
|
Spent
voluntarily
0.32 |
GDP
0.2 |
raw
material
0.2 |
|||||
Total tax
0.28 |
GDP
0.16 |
raw
material
0.16 |
||||||
Waste
0.028 |
InfraS
0.056 |
Benefits
0.056 |
GDP
0.14 |
|||||
Table 2. Recycling of GDP with VAT and income tax at 30% (Units=Trillion £GB)
Initial GDP=1Tr£
|
||||||||
Inc tax
0.3
|
Net income
0.7
|
|||||||
VATable spending
0.35 |
VAT exempt (rent, food)
0.35 |
|||||||
VAT
0.105
|
Spent
voluntarily
0.245 |
GDP
0.175 |
Raw
material
0.175 |
|||||
Total tax
0.405 |
GDP
0.1225 |
Raw
material
0.1225 |
||||||
Waste
0.04 |
InfraS
0.081 |
Benefits
0.081 |
GDP
0.203 |
|||||
References:
[3] http://www.investopedia.com/terms/g/gdp.asp
[5] Strictly speaking the recycled GDP will itself recycle after
splitting into 'waste', 'infrastructure' etc., adding progressively smaller
amounts to GDP with each cycle: 0.556, 0.309, 0.172, 0.096, etc.. But for simplicity I consider only one
cycle through the table for that is sufficient to make the argument. For the
higher tax rate the additional GDP with successive cycles is: 0.582, 0.339,
0.198, 0.115, etc..
No comments:
Post a Comment